Arthur Seldon's Contribution to Freedom
- Norman Barry, The Freeman, April 2006
Some politicians, so important today, are forgotten
by next year. Events that seem so cataclysmic in
our own times are soon but distant memories. But
the great ideas live on long after their authors'death.We
must put into that category the work of Arthur Seldon-co-founder, with Lord Harris of High Cross, of the
Institute of Economic Affairs (IEA), London-whose death last October 11, at age
89, we mourn.
From obscurity and complete intellec
tual unfashionability throughout the
1950s and 1960s, Seldon and a distin
guished cadre of writers managed to
influence a whole generation of econo
mists and writers on the market and limited government. At a time when the
intellectual world was dominated by the
Keynesian-collectivist consensus, Seldon
successfully educated a new generation
into a fresh way of thinking and introduced to a British audience such "foreign" economists as Milton Friedman and
F A. Hayek. And though not naturally a conservative
he always called himself an Old Liberal--he was a great
influence on Margaret Thatcher, and indeed many of her
policies originated in Lord North Street, Westminster,
London, home of the IEA.
Born in 1916 into relative poverty to Jewish immi
grant parents in the East End of London, Seldon worked
his way into the London School of Economics (LSE),
where he came under the influence of Hayek, a recent
ly appointed professor. It was an influence that was never
to desert him. He quickly learned that almost everything
the government does the market and the private sector could do better. Most important, he realized that if you
want to advance the interests of the working class, free
market capitalism always beats the government. This was
the beginning of a lifelong campaign against state welfare. From his earliest days he understood that sponta
neous working-class organizations like the friendly
societies provided better health care, old-
age pensions, and unemployment benefits
than the vast state bureaucracies that
replaced them.
The IEA was set up in 1957, with the
backing of a prosperous chicken farmer,
Antony Fisher. Fisher, a convinced free-
marketer, had learned from Hayek that to
influence events, it is better not to go into
politics, but rather to produce ideas. That is why he financed the IEA and many
other free-market think tanks throughout
the world.
As editorial director, Seldon quickly set
about recruiting some of the best names
in free-market ideas. He created a "house
style" that was remarkable: he managed to persuade
writers to communicate in simple, concise prose
without in any way sacrificing the rigor of their arguments. As one who was a little frustrated at seeing his
virginal text almost violated by the red pen of Arthur
Seldon, I quickly came to realize that he was right all
along and that he had transformed yet another dreary
academic paper into something that might even attract the attention of the conventional leftwing press.
Someone very receptive to Seldon's approach was
Milton Friedman, who always had a genius for convey-
ing complex ideas in lucid prose. Friedman led the IEA's
onslaught on Keynesianism from the early 1960s. One of
the many reasons for the "New Right's" eventual triumph over the Old Left was the clarity, as well as the
perspicacity, of its arguments. Compared to the turgid
and incomprehensible style of the typical unreadable
Oxbridge academic publication, a piece from the IEA
was always intellectually exciting and extraordinarily
well-written.
Ever anxious to keep his readers up
to date with new thinking, Seldon
quickly saw the significance of Public
Choice theory, which was emerging in
the 1960s. Distrustful of politicians, he
never believed that they were disinterested promoters of the public good, but
rather were self-interested utility maximizers beholden to interest groups that
made their careers possible. So naturally
he was attracted to American theorists
like James Buchanan (a Nobel Prize
winner in 1986) and Gordon Tullock.
In fact, some of their book-length
works were published in easily accessible form by the IEA.
Seldon was a natural anarchist who
delighted in offending the statist establishment. This reached its apogee in
1968 with the publication of Mike
Cooper and Tony Culyer's The Price of Blood. This presented the quite shocking idea that shortages in hospitals would be solved if that precious human
commodity were bought and sold like any other good.
This argument offended the sentimentalists, who
believed that an inexhaustible supply of altruism was just waiting to be tapped, and the welfare establishment,
which did not want the intervention of the tasteless and
unruly market into an area that was the exclusive preserve of the well-meaning state.
Seldon himself was a prolific writer. His best work
was probably on welfare policy, in which he relentlessly
exposed the denial of choice and the dull inefficiency
that the state produced in health and pensions. His first
paper for the IEA was a stunning piece on the inequities
and inefficiencies of the state pension system, a subject
that was to bother him all his life. In the 1980s he published some remarkable research
which indicated that the British public preferred more choice and private
provision in welfare and was prepared
to pay for it. All this is concealed in
the vote-maximizing practices that
go on in regular elections. He was an
indefatigable proponent, with his
wife, Marjorie, of Friedman's idea of
vouchers in education. Again, this
illustrated his desire that state bureaucracies and trade unions should be
removed from decisions that affect
ordinary people and their families.
But perhaps his finest work was the
sadly neglected book Capitalism
(1990). Here he celebrated not only
the market system's efficiency, but
also its contribution to human freedom. He was working to the end
against the state. His seven-volume
works are being completed by the IEA, and only then will a full evaluation be possible.
Seldon was a prominent member of the Mont
Pelerin Society and an honorary fellow of the LSE and
the private University of Buckingham, which was
fathered by the IEA. He will be sadly missed.
Norman Barry (norman.barry@buckin2ham.ac.uk) is a professor of social
and political theory at the University of Buckingham, UK, the country's
only private university. An earlier version of this article was published in the
Financial Times, London. October 25, 2005.
|